(click to enlarge)
Tuesday, 27 May 2014
Democracy still blows (feebly) from the West
A very quick look at EU elections. With the important exceptions of the UK, Netherlands and Portugal, turnout, which was overall low, was above average in western Europe. It was very disappointing in eastern Europe (would be curious if there is divide between east and west Germany). For what regards Portugal, I am puzzled. Official numbers put the number of electors at 9.456.201 on the national territory (excluding Portuguese abroad). With a resident population above 18 of approximately 8.4 millions (an upper bound on the number of electors) it looks like Portugal should clean the electoral lists.
Sunday, 25 May 2014
A few thoughts on Portugal and the Euro
Consensus exists on what should be the present and future path of the the Portuguese economy. Portugal needs to reach a state of sustained current account surpluses and simultaneously reabsorb a large number of unemployed while deleveraging the balance sheets of the Households, the Government and the Corporations (see Figure 1).
Where we see opinions differ vividly is in the actions to implement this path. One end of the opinion spectrum thinks that Portugal should exit the euro, regain monetary policy autonomy, stay in the common market with a devalued escudo and restructure national liabilities. The other end believes that structural reforms coupled with a medium-term consolidation anchored in a coherent euro membership will rebalance and relaunch the economy.
The pro-euro-exit narrative follows the textbook description of a devaluation. Real wages will fall, the real exchange rate will depreciate. This will favour temporarily (2-3 years?) employment and the tradable sector. Yes but... economies have evolved faster than textbooks and supply chains, increasing the import content of exports, have likely changed the importance of the nominal exchange rate in determining the trade balance. Portugal is no different and is highly integrated with other producers in Spain, Germany Italy and France. Its energy trade balance is negative (although has improved). Not so sure a nominal devaluation would improve significantly the trade balance (lower labor costs will help). In any case, even with a national currency, the most likely exchange rate arrangement with the rest of the common market would be a fixed or managed exchange regime that de facto will subordinate national monetary policy to the ECB. The extra degree of freedom, which is more a fraction of a degree of freedom, would be that Portugal could change the central parity (value) relative to the euro. One certainty is that financial markets will reflect this possibility in higher interest rates. All assets and liabilities denominated in euro (and other currencies) that do not include the contingency of a change in denomination (if they exist) will see their value increase in terms of the new currency. Given the large negative investment position, strongly biased toward debt, Portugal will need to restructure its liabilities. The restructuring would also be reflected into higher interest rates. The capacity to attract foreign investment will decrease. Finally the exit from the euro and the permanence in the common market is not an option contemplated by the treaties and will have to be negotiated with the rest of the EU members. Would it be a temporary exit with a subsequent medium term strategy to attain the conditions to be part of the euro at a later date, or would it be a change of course towards a more standalone posture vis-a-vis Europe and the World? This uncertainty will imply a disorderly period and diminish any positive effects of the devaluation.
It is also true that the adjustment within the euro is difficult. It requires well functioning markets and a coherent currency area. By well functioning I mean markets that permit adjustment through the demand-supply mechanism and deliver competitive outcomes. Ireland for example appears to have better functioning markets than Portugal. This did not protect Ireland from the consequences of a tremendous financial shock but helped to quicken the adjustment relative to Portugal. (see Figure 2) The policy prescriptions to improve labor markets functioning are reforms that increase job flexibility and maintain workers protection. Fairness suggests to address both legs, flexibility and protection, simultaneously. The policy prescriptions for better functioning goods markets are to increase competition in the non-tradable and networks sectors. We need to recognise that scale and some market power can be a source of R&D and innovation especially in the ITC and energy sector. If this is the case, the creation of integrated pan-european markets in the network industries can break national resistance to better competition (which is very strong), allow sufficient scale for innovation and simultaneously permit European countries to operate on a level playing field by facing similar telecommunication and energy costs. This is the solution the euro area has adopted with the Banking Union to ensure that firms face similar competitive conditions in crucial inputs such as financial services and credit. The latter goes beyond the competition argument as it also aim at improving the transmission of monetary policy across the euro area. When fully implemented, Portugal like the other periphery countries, will see credit supply conditions improve and be at par with other euro members. Improving competition in the network sectors will help the rebalancing towards the tradable sector. It might not be sufficient to reabsorb sufficiently rapidly the large number of unskilled unemployed. (Can we find non-resident resources to reabsorb the unemployed coming out of the construction sector by finding resources to repair and maintain the existing stock of houses?) To be credible (in the sense of having a positive probability of success), the deleveraging and consolidations processes cannot be made unconditional to the state of the economy. They need to be designed around sound measures of structural unemployment and potential output level and growth. (For example some measures put the structural unemployment rate in Portugal at approximately 13% based on a non accelerating nominal wage model: nominal wages do not decrease therefore the unemployment rate is structural. Assume just for a moment that nominal wages never decrease, then there is no upper bound to the structural unemployment rate measured with this model.) Fiscal consolidation must also be made progressive to have as low as possible recessionary effects and ensure social cohesion and fairness.
A note on the euro. Yes we lost the possibility to devalue against other euro members. But was it really such a bonanza to devalue in the past? (read this older post). Yes the nominal convergence started in the mid 1990's towards German rates caused a boom that the periphery was not capable to channel towards higher productivity capital. Portuguese 10 years government bonds went from 11.8% in 1995q1 to 4% in 1999q1. But German interest rates on Bunds went from 7.4% to 4% in the same period: there were (and are) forces beyond the euro at play. Yes some euro zone members do not fully accept that to a current account deficit must correspond a current account surplus. And now the euro-area has the largest current account surplus in the World. With a fairly high unemployment rate. One certainty: international imbalances require international cooperation. Another certainty: inter-nations imbalances within a currency area require its members to have coherent policies.
Figure 1 (click to enlarge)
Figure 2 (click to enlarge)
Wednesday, 21 May 2014
The reform of the state in the troika and in the post-troika periods
The reform of the state has been set as one of the primary
goals of the adjustment program, as a way to avoid future problems of this
sort. The notion of reform of the state is very broad, and different meanings
have been attached to it: better functioning of the civil service structure
(how the Government does it), redefinition of the scope of Government
intervention (what the Government does) and the depth of Government
intervention (which part is done by the Government and which part is done by
the private sector). This way of splitting the several notions of Government
reform has never been clear in the political (and policy) discussions about the
reform of the state. The document the Government made publicly available is, in
this respect, a mix of all three, in a random order, as it clearly resulted
from joining contributions from different sources (ministries, I guess).
The changes during the troika period along these dimensions
were uneven.
On the internal procedures of the Government, several
measures have been adopted to increased the control of the ministry of finance
over the spending ability of individual organisms inside civil service, which
are expected to have a long term effect, and many short-term measures
(restrictions on what can be done, and how much can be spent) were implemented.
Still, a long road waits for the post-troika period. In particular, one point
that has been mentioned in several discussions about the issue (check the Sextas da Reforma debates) is the fragmentation
of relationships between civil service organisms and the ministry of finance.
In terms of redefining the scope of Government, there was no
mention about it but for some privatizations that were set as a commitment in
the Memorandum of Understanding. In all other areas, in the several documents
produced, it was very clear that each minister had (has) if anything a desire
to increase the scope of intervention. The discussion of the scope of
Government is unlikely to occur in the post-troika period.
Finally, the depth of intervention was the area where more
discussion took place, even though in an unstructured manner. The main example is
given by pensions – where cuts and “generational fairness” (largely undefined
in their meaning) are a redefinition of the “depth” of public intervention in
the pension system.
A different type of action, that has been termed “reform”
somewhat too much, is improvement on what the Government does without changing
internal procedures, the scope or the depth of intervention – things like
changing justice codes, implementing centralized electronic procurement,
lowering prices of outsourced services. These hardly constitute a “reform”,
they are just better management of what is done. These have been the main focus
of action as it is where it becomes easier to find what consultants love, “quick
wins”, but they are also easily reversible in the post-troika period.
Overall, some progress has been made, more by outside
pressure or by financial pressure, not really on a structured decision making
process with engagement of society on state reform. Even the efforts may stop
in an election year. What is mostly needed is a process, a political process,
by which important decisions on scope and depth of Government intervention need
to be discussed and then translated into policy action.
Author: Pedro Pita Barros
Tuesday, 20 May 2014
The Post-Troika Portugal - a view from the past
Richard Sylla’s paper,
“Early US Struggles with Fiscal Federalism:
Lessons for Europe?”[1],
provides an excellent background regarding European sovereign states and the
euro common currency in comparison to the situation of the United States 200
years ago. The young United States came
out of the War of Independence heavily indebted, and it took great effort to
put the country onto the financial path that led to economic growth and prosperity.
From 1781 to ’84 Finance Superintendent
Robert Morris made a great effort to bring order to the Treasury but was unable
to sort out the prevailing chaos. There
were many tasks that needed to be addressed simultaneously, including
stabilizing the public finance, managing the war debt, and establishing a
stable currency, a central bank, a complete banking system, a stock exchange,
and promoting businesses that could lead production, employment, and exports
forward. These became possible only
following the introduction, in 1790, of the financial program of the first Treasury
Secretary (Finance Minister), Alexander Hamilton.
Congress approved a new Constitution for
the Union in 1788, while Hamilton’s proposals called for assuming the
individual American States’ debts as a national debt, thereby promoting
cohesion to the cause of American independence.
New lending was negotiated and secured to service that national debt,
which contributed to global respectability and a national reputation; and a
fiscal system with import duties was implemented to balance the needs of the
entire financial system. The Bank of the
United States was founded in 1791 with the central-bank function of
lender-of-last-resort; the U.S. Mint was founded in 1792 in Philadelphia to
provide a stable currency based on the “dollar”; and in the same year the New
York Stock Exchange was created to serve the existing corporate structure and
nurture the next generation of start-ups.
The optimist would say that the political
parallels with today’s Europe and America’s historical success story predict
the way forward for the many independent EU Member States. The euro zone has a stable currency and there
is an issuing central bank. If a shared
public debt was one of the prices of achieving the American Union, shared
public debt is likewise one of the prices of achieving the European Union. And if there are social cleavages in Europe,
surely slavery was a greater one in America.
Can European national states take any comfort or hope in these parallels
regarding the solution of financial problems?
Sylla’s paper recognizes that in addition
to the obvious historical similarities there are also considerable
differences. Europe lacks a European
Constitution. Europe also lacks any
constitutional principles on which to construct a shared Union public debt, nor
are there any mechanisms compelling the individual states to honor such a
notion at all. Moreover, even as late as the 1840s the Federal Union refused to
bail out certain financially profligate American states, forcing them to face
up to their own responsibilities.
American cohesion and political will was
much stronger in the aftermath of its recently-won independence than it is on
the old continent, where bitter rivalry and hostility have been constant
factors down through centuries of history. But in the earlier days, lenders
were more favorable to the bellicose victors in a new and growing nation, it
seems, than they are today in the presence of partner nations who have desires
for socially beneficial programs, in peace for several decades.
Unlike the United States, Europe is an
amalgamation of independent nations and disparate governments, lacking the
centralized power to define and enforce a common fiscal policy. This forces each European state to devise its
own such policy according to its own needs for servicing its own public debt –
as well as according to varying constitutional principles, which may not view
public debt commitment in the same way.
Credibility is also a crucial factor that
differs dramatically between a new-born nation and a complex political
construct that has emerged largely as the result of the Marshall Plan,
following two long and bloody conflicts that were essentially “European civil
wars”, which devastated the “winners” and “losers” alike.
As an independent European state, Portugal
has a reputation to defend as well as economic growth targets to reach – in an
institutional context that differs greatly from the framework and goals of a
common European Treasury.
Author: Maria Eugénia Mata
[1] Comparative Economic Studies, 2014, Spring:
1-19. I thank Prof. Sylla for allowing
me access to the forthcoming paper, and discussion.
Monday, 19 May 2014
Three years of Troika: Telecommunications Markets
The Memorandum of
Understanding of 17 May 2011 contained a handful of measures intended to
increase competitiveness and easy of entry to telecommunications markets in
Portugal. None of these measures had to do directly with the economic crisis,
but took up existing developments and conflicts with the European Commission.
The first of these
measures was to implement the European Commission’s “Better Regulation
Directive” of 2009, increasing the independence of ICP-Anacom, the Portuguese
telecoms regulator. By 2012 this issue was solved, even though rules under the
“Citizen’s Rights Directive” of 2002 had still not been satisfactorily
implemented.
The second measure
was the auctioning of more radio spectrum (the previous analog TV spectrum, for
fourth-generation data services) in order to increase the possibility of entry,
and the reduction of mobile termination rates. The auction was performed, and
as it could be expected in the middle of a deep economic crisis, the final bids
were equal to the minimum prices set by ICP-Anacom and no entry occurred.
Mobile termination rates were further reduced, but this was part of a
long-planned regulatory process that has been ongoing for a decade.
The third point was
the issue of the universal service provider for fixed telephony. The previous
government had renewed the universal service concession of Portugal Telecom,
without having run a competitive process as by now was mandatory by European
Law. In 2013, ICP-Anacom ran a competition which was won by Zon-Optimus, who
will become the universal service provider.
The last point on
the list were measures to facilitate consumer switching between fixed
communications provider, such as standardized contracts, and to reduce entry
barriers for now providers. To our best knowledge, no additional measures have
been put in place in this respect.
The main developments
in the market actually had little to do with the Troika’s presence. First,
commercial strategies of communications providers changed, from offering
services such as fixed telephony and broadband, TV, and mobile telephony
separately, to selling them all together as a quadruple-play bundle.
This move tended to
favour companies active in both the fixed and mobile markets, and as such may
have led to the long-rumoured merger between the mobile operator Optimus (of
Sonaecom, also with a small fixed-line business) and the cable TV operator Zon
(ex TV-Cabo) to finally advance. As a result, the communications market in
Portugal is getting closer to being a duopoly, even if the mobile operator
Vodafone and the cable operator Cabovisão continue to have significant market
shares in their respective segments.
On the other hand, no
decision about regulation of access to next-generation networks (fibre or cable
networks under the latest standard), a decisive issue for the development of
the market, has been taken, nor has this issue been present in the Memorandum
of Understanding. The reason for this delay could be that the European
Commission’s Recommendation on Relevant Markets, the list of markets to be
regulated, itself was under review (a draft recommendation has been published
in early 2014, but the process is not yet finished).
Summing up, the
presence of the Troika has not led to developments in Portuguese communications
markets that would not have happened anyway, and the most important issue for
the future development of the market, access to next-generation networks, is
not yet resolved.
Author: Steffen Hoernig
Sunday, 18 May 2014
The “Troika” and the Portuguese agriculture
During the
nineties of last century a new concept emerged in the agricultural economics
literature: rural renaissance. In a simplified way this new concept can be
defined as a specific phase in the economic development process of affluent
societies, in which the rural world gains higher relative importance. The rural
world now includes not only the traditional agricultural activity, but also many
of the economic activities usually located in the large urban communities. In
other words it means the migration of industries and services from large
centers to rural areas. And this movement is also accompanied by the
renaissance of agriculture itself, both in terms of new farmers and new technologies.
References to
renewed agricultural practices have recently been made in Portugal. More
specifically it has been said that a few subsectors within agriculture have
witnessed important rates of growth in production.
In order to test
the existence of such evolution, we looked at the main economic indicators for
agriculture in the twenty first century, namely the Output of Agricultural
Industry (OAI), the Gross Value Added (GVA), the Gross Fixed Capital Formation
(GFCF) and Agricultural Labor Input (ALI). Moreover we tried to identify the
subsectors where a notorious production growth could have taken place.
In Table 1 it is not possible to detect clear
tendencies of growth or contraction either for OAI or GVA. The fluctuations
observed must be due to weather randomness rather than any other factor. On the
contrary GFCF registers a fall of 2.3% during the period.
These same performances
are well illustrated in Figure 1.
Table 1 - OUTPUT,
VALUE ADDED, FIXED CAPITAL FORMATION AND LABOR USE IN AGRICULTURE, Portugal,
2000 -2013
Year
|
Output of the Agricultural Industry
(basic prices)
|
Gross Value Added
|
Gross Fixed Capital Formation
|
Agricultural Labour Input
|
||
Constant prices of 2006
|
Total
|
Salaried
|
Non-salaried
|
|||
106 Euro
|
103 AWU
|
|||||
2000
|
5,926.0
|
2,684.0
|
869.5
|
496.8
|
80.8
|
415.9
|
2001
|
5,971.9
|
2,585.6
|
951.4
|
500.1
|
81.5
|
418.7
|
2002
|
6,272.9
|
2,897.2
|
914.0
|
473.7
|
77.2
|
396.5
|
2003
|
5,986.5
|
2,666.0
|
840.9
|
472.6
|
78.2
|
394.4
|
2004
|
6,429.5
|
2,967.3
|
891.4
|
446.8
|
78.8
|
368.1
|
2005
|
5,908.2
|
2,529.2
|
769.2
|
437.3
|
79.4
|
357.9
|
2006
|
6,040.3
|
2,713.9
|
751.6
|
425.9
|
77.8
|
348.1
|
2007
|
6,031.3
|
2,616.0
|
772.4
|
416.1
|
73.4
|
342.7
|
2008
|
6,189.0
|
2,735.4
|
727.5
|
409.8
|
72.7
|
337.1
|
2009
|
6,150.8
|
2,642.5
|
635.5
|
403.5
|
69.6
|
333.9
|
2010
|
6,116.4
|
2,613.8
|
658.1
|
371.3
|
70.8
|
300.5
|
2011Po
|
6,036.6
|
2,556.3
|
648.5
|
356.8
|
68.0
|
288.8
|
2012Po
|
6,021.0
|
2,494.9
|
642.5
|
355.8
|
65.2
|
290.6
|
2013f
|
6,048.8
|
2,585.2
|
x
|
354.1
|
62.4
|
291.6
|
Source: INE
AWU – annual work units; Po – provisional data; f
- forecast
In Table 1 it
can also be seen that, contrary to output, total labor input, suffered a fall
of about 2.6% annually. Curiously, and has in Figure 2 shows, there is a
slowdown in the fall of labor input in the last three years of the period
(2011-2013), which has to be attributed to the light increase in non-salaried
labor in those years.
Can it be the
case that the increase in self employed labor denotes some renaissance in the Portuguese
agricultural sector? And if yes is it a reaction to the unemployment increase
in other sectors of the economy as a consequence of the policy measures of the
“Program of Economic and Financial Adjustment” imposed by the Troika?
The empirical
evidence above does not seem enough for a clear cut positive answer, even
because the level of total agricultural output did not show significant changes.
At most it can be said that the effects of the policy measures had a positive indirect
impact on the establishment of new farmers. And this new blood (both in terms
of entrepreneurs and technology) may be responsible for the growth dynamics felt
in some subsectors of production.
Table 2 shows
the performance of some of the most important subsectors of crop production, as
well as the three classic subsectors of animal production.
Table 2 – EVOLUTION
OF AGRICULTURAL OUTPUT IN SELECTED SUBSECTORS,
Portugal,
2000-2013
Source:
INE ; P – provisional data; f - forecast
Year
|
Crop Output
|
Animal Products
|
||||||||
Total
|
Fresh Vegetables
|
Fresh Fruits (except citrus, subtropical, grapes and
olives)
|
Wine
|
Olives
|
Olive Oil
|
Total
|
Meat
|
Milk
|
Eggs
|
|
106
Euro (constant prices of 2006)
|
||||||||||
2000
|
3,192.3
|
502.7
|
446.5
|
401.3
|
136.5
|
5.2
|
2,455.8
|
1,603.9
|
741.5
|
91.0
|
2001
|
3,243.1
|
505.5
|
433.1
|
449.2
|
93.2
|
3.5
|
2,442.1
|
1,607.5
|
717.8
|
96.6
|
2002
|
3,442.0
|
567.0
|
513.5
|
357.5
|
106.2
|
3.1
|
2,523.0
|
1,652.9
|
752.4
|
97.5
|
2003
|
3,267.8
|
579.7
|
460.2
|
356.5
|
108.9
|
2.8
|
2,424.5
|
1,600.3
|
706.8
|
99.0
|
2004
|
3,478.7
|
581.7
|
479.5
|
384.0
|
132.7
|
5.2
|
2,645.9
|
1,799.0
|
728.0
|
102.9
|
2005
|
3,014.6
|
539.6
|
474.7
|
385.7
|
114.1
|
4.5
|
2,594.9
|
1,736.7
|
750.9
|
90.5
|
2006
|
3,317.2
|
534.5
|
506.3
|
398.5
|
147.8
|
3.9
|
2,417.7
|
1,582.4
|
727.0
|
91.5
|
2007
|
3,274.4
|
552.9
|
454.0
|
383.6
|
227.4
|
6.4
|
2,464.0
|
1,637.1
|
717.3
|
91.9
|
2008
|
3,348.1
|
563.2
|
492.3
|
372.7
|
254.4
|
7.0
|
2,517.9
|
1,676.1
|
731.8
|
93.3
|
2009
|
3,425.0
|
585.1
|
573.8
|
365.8
|
336.0
|
13.9
|
2,442.0
|
1,607.2
|
725.7
|
92.4
|
2010
|
3,450.3
|
600.5
|
526.5
|
419.4
|
376.4
|
15.3
|
2,398.6
|
1,572.0
|
708.1
|
98.8
|
2011P
|
3,421.6
|
597.3
|
569.4
|
345.6
|
419.9
|
18.8
|
2,355.2
|
1,538.9
|
704.9
|
92.9
|
2012P
|
3,435.6
|
607.5
|
512.5
|
372.1
|
380.3
|
14.9
|
2,332.4
|
1,516.5
|
710.5
|
90.6
|
2013f
|
3,583.7
|
592.5
|
580.9
|
376.2
|
462.8
|
17.9
|
2,242.0
|
1,444.1
|
682.1
|
95.4
|
The table shows that total crop production growth is almost entirely
matched by the decrease in animal products, thus confirming the above mentioned
stagnation of total agricultural output. But it is also evident that vegetables,
fresh fruits and olive trees production have sizable increments (from1.3% annually
for vegetables to 9.9% for olive oil).
These results definitely helped the good performance of the trade
balance in recent years. It was in fact in the crop subsectors of Table 2 that
exports grew more significantly. Figures in Table 3 cannot be compared with the
above data because the lack of direct information on exports in national and
EUROSTAT Statistics forced us to use FAO figures. Besides being expressed in US
dollars, product typology does not coincide.
Table 3 – EVOLUTION
OF EXPORTS OF SELECTED AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS,
Portugal
2000-2011
Year
|
Wine
|
Olive Oil
|
Preserved vegetables
|
Frozen vegetables
|
1000 US dollars
|
||||
2000
|
468,958
|
58,326
|
13,145
|
13,188
|
2001
|
435,559
|
50,101
|
16,548
|
15,335
|
2002
|
480,770
|
46,478
|
18,027
|
19,157
|
2003
|
602,619
|
55,582
|
X
|
20,516
|
2004
|
660,693
|
94,474
|
24,361
|
26,919
|
2005
|
653,608
|
117,959
|
24,411
|
30,026
|
2006
|
665,775
|
144,378
|
X
|
41,044
|
2007
|
818,494
|
151,790
|
35,831
|
53,422
|
2008
|
851,038
|
191,323
|
55,578
|
70,473
|
2009
|
760,776
|
168,612
|
55,187
|
57,269
|
2010
|
806,723
|
211,555
|
51,446
|
43,955
|
2011
|
907,464
|
271,056
|
57,341
|
55,571
|
Source: FAO
The information in the table entirely confirms what was said. To point
out only the fact that the value of olive oil exports in 2011 allowed for a first
positive trade balance.
We can then conclude that the policy measures in the “Program of
Economic and Financial Adjustment” did not directly affect the Portuguese
agricultural sector. On the contrary the dynamic behavior of some subsectors of
crop production definitely fitted one of the objectives of such program: the improvement of the Portuguese trade
balance.
Author: Fernando Brito Soares
Author: Fernando Brito Soares
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)